Economics Books » Financial Crisis

The best books on Financial Speculation

recommended by John Gapper

How To Be a Rogue Trader by John Gapper

How To Be a Rogue Trader
by John Gapper

Read

We all have a bit of the rogue trader in us. So says the chief business commentator of the FT, who tells us about the greed, vanity and weakness that can lead to financial disaster. He picks the best books on financial speculation.

How To Be a Rogue Trader by John Gapper

How To Be a Rogue Trader
by John Gapper

Read
Buy all books

When the financial markets crash, whether it’s in 1929 or 1973 or 2008, people get angry. But in your book, How To Be a Rogue Trader, you imply that financial speculation is baked into the human character. We get the booms and busts that we deserve, and even that we want. So are we fools or hypocrites, or both?

We always say afterwards, “How could it possibly have happened? It’s an outrage! Why weren’t we stopped?” But at the time we all want our houses to rise in price. We all fear losing face to the neighbour we meet at the dinner party who’s done better from real estate speculation than we have. The pattern time and time again is that you have the speculators, who draw in the elite group, and then, as the speculation continues, everybody wants to be part of it, everybody thinks, “Oh I’m just a little bit behind, I need to get in.”

You can find plenty of evidence from psychological and behavioural research that we are to some extent programmed to act in crowds – to follow the crowd towards what we think will be a reward. Like birds and bees. Whether in a coordinated fashion, or individually for the good of the species.

These speculative peaks repeat themselves down history. People say, “It will never happen again.” And then it does – you just have to wait a decade or two for people to forget sufficiently. At some point you have got to conclude that we are programmed to behave in this way. Because we enjoy it. And because some people can make an enormous amount of money in bubbles if they get it right.

And, presumably, because so many people think they have some sort of edge over the others in the market – better information, better instincts, better judgement, better models. Is that always an illusion?

There is some interesting academic work that suggests you could run a hedge fund by flipping a coin, literally flipping a coin, risking your capital on the outcome, and if you model the way that fund would perform, it would perform very well at low volatility for seven years. And then go bang. The nice name for this is “informationless investing”. It can give your hedge fund a long enough life for you to make an enormous amount of money, and for your investors to lose it all.

Which is an opportune moment to introduce your first book, Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowd by Charles MacKay. It sounds as though we haven’t even digested what Mackay was trying to tell us in 1841.

It’s a very patchy book, but it leads off with three classic financial booms and busts – tulip mania in Holland, the Mississippi scheme in 18th century France, and the South Sea Bubble. MacKay was a journalist with a fine tabloid style, and he writes it all up very entertainingly. He gets the eyewitness quotes and he finds the human foibles.

And, because he was the first person to collect these episodes, his book has become the source material for a lot of later works that are more scholarly and more rigorous. And yes, when you read Mackay, you do think, “Oh my goodness, this is what’s happening now.” There are extraordinary parallels.

For example?

In periods of speculation, people start trading derivatives of whatever the primary commodity might be. During the South Sea Bubble they were speculating not only on sailcloth for the expeditions, but on options to buy the sailcloth.

James Surowiecki wrote a recent book called The Wisdom of Crowds. Are the wisdom and the madness reconcilable?

Surowiecki talks about the way in which crowds of people making independent judgements can come up with good decisions. But if you have a coordinated mass hysteria, that’s something completely different.

And it presumes a coordinator. Your next book, Anthony Trollope’s The Way We Live Now, is also about speculation – but it’s as much about manipulation, isn’t it?

Absolutely. And, slightly atypically for Trollope, it is a book written in a spirit of moral disgust. Trollope generally takes a detached, somewhat comic or ironic view of society. But here we have contempt for the state of Victorian Britain in 1875.

Augustus Melmotte, the tycoon at the centre of the story, is a great character: A mysterious outsider with a bullying, charming, intimidating presence. He promises money and riches to London’s decadent and foppish aristocrats. He is really a speculator in railway bonds, with an American shyster, Hamilton K Fisker, as his partner. Aristocrats crowd on to his boards, as baubles, for the money.

Support Five Books

Five Books interviews are expensive to produce. If you're enjoying this interview, please support us by .

You sense an entire class of society wanting to be corrupted, wanting to believe in this man. Melmotte is the precursor of modern figures such as Bob Maxwell and Bernie Madoff, who bully or charm you into believing they have the key to boundless riches.

It’s hard to think of another novel about finance that works quite so well.

Other writers have tried to capture the world of high finance, and failed, because finance is abstract and complicated. Trollope succeeded because his real interest was in bringing to life the way that money could change human character. There’s nothing abstract or complicated about greed, vanity and weakness. Tom Wolfe managed something similar a century later with The Bonfire of the Vanities.

Greed, vanity and weakness are also, to some extent, the themes of John Kenneth Galbraith’s The Great Crash 1929. Do you admire Galbraith as an economist?

The book shows his talent as a popular economist. It’s not chiefly a work of economics, though it does analyse the causes of the Great Depression. It’s more a work of history, almost of journalism. For an academic, Galbraith writes unusually well.

Does the book have predictive value? Could you have read it in 2005 and said “it looks like we’ve got another crash approaching”?

When you open this book, it starts with real estate speculation in Florida. Everybody is rushing down there because they believe Florida real estate is going to have an enormous boom. They are speculating in derivatives on it. The parallels could hardly be more precise.

“There’s nothing abstract or complicated about greed, vanity and weakness”

Galbraith also draws out well the way in which one of the top bankers of the day, Charles Mitchell of National City Bank, together with Richard Whitney, head of the New York Stock Exchange, contrived to prolong the period of financial speculation. After the crash, these two became the symbols of the financial class’s malfeasance. They were prosecuted and reputationally ruined. Whitney was sent to Sing Sing [prison]. There, the parallel breaks down. No senior banker has faced such harsh justice this time.

Did the crash of 1929 fundamentally change American markets?

Galbraith didn’t go so far as to say that it could never happen again. But he did conclude that Wall Street would never be trusted in the same way. Instead, America would trust new institutions and regulations – first and foremost the Securities and Exchange Commission.

But if you fast-forward to the past decade, you find that the SEC had become ineffectual. And the Federal Reserve, at least under Alan Greenspan, was treating derivatives as though they were reducing and distributing risk, rather than creating it. So with benefit of hindsight, you have to say that Wall Street came through the Great Crash without being fundamentally changed.

Your next book, When Genius Failed, by Roger Lowenstein, is about the downfall of John Meriwether’s hedge fund, Long-Term Capital Management, in 1998 – which in some ways prefigured the crash of 2008.

The Fed itself did not bail out LTCM, but it was worried enough to get a bunch of big banks into the room and say, “Would you care to chip in and save this thing?” Which they obligingly did – and then liquidated it. The Fed foresaw that the failure of a single big hedge fund could send shock waves through the entire financial system. The issue of systemic risk was highlighted.

LTCM was a leading indicator in another way. Its principals didn’t believe they were speculating. They believed they had risk models that worked. As they saw it, they were arbitraging divergences between markets and instruments that were bound to come back in line, based on the historical data. And because they thought the risk was so controlled, the traders leveraged up enormously, placed huge bets, thanks to the magic of derivatives.

What LTCM left out of its calculations was what we now called “fat tail” or “black swan” events. Those came with the crises in East Asia and in Russia in 1997-98. A lot of LTCM’s trades not only went wrong, but went wrong simultaneously across lots of different markets. The firm collapsed. Yet even as it was going down, John Meriwether – who appears in Michael Lewis’s Liars Poker as the man who took the liar’s poker bets – still believed that his bets were the right ones, if he only he had had more time and more money. He had a liquidity problem. But it was the markets that were wrong.

Lowenstein explains in very elegant terms some pretty complicated concepts involving derivatives, Black-Scholes [financial model] and trading. He captures the characters. But it’s less a character book than a book about this thing that many people hadn’t heard of, bubbling up within the financial system. Before LTCM, nobody outside the elite of Wall Street had any idea of the importance of derivatives. But inside this elite, a whole class of traders was starting to think of financial markets in completely different terms.

Do you think Meriwether really believed in the truth of his models? Or was it enough that he had found a better way of fooling people?

Meriwether is a stone-cold gambler. I think what he believed was that he’d found a way to twist the odds in the casino, using models that only a few brainiacs could understand. He got people on his side who knew more sophisticated ways to place bets on financial markets than even central banks did.

So, as he thought, he had the intelligent money on his side, and the uninformed betting against him, and that made for pretty good odds. And indeed, he was right for a long time. It worked brilliantly for four years. And then it went bang.

It seems almost paradoxical that LTCM should have gone bust by betting against volatility, which is what market arbitrage amounts to.

It’s a hazard of having high-powered economists as strategists. They always want to short volatility. They believe that the markets are going to come to their senses. It’s reverse speculation, if you like. The underlying idea is that other people panic, and that’s why markets go crazy. If you can think through all the noise, you can bet against them and win. The problem is, of course, that the markets can stay crazy a lot longer than you can stay solvent.

Which brings us almost up to the present day, and your last book, All The Devils Are Here by Bethany McLean and Joe Nocera, about the crash of 2008. Is the title ironic?

It comes from The Tempest: “Hell is empty / And all the devils are here”.

There are lots of really good books about the recent financial crisis, by Andrew Ross Sorkin, Roger Lowenstein, William D Cohan and others. I’ve picked McLean and Nocera because they give a broad view, rather as Galbraith did for 1929. They tie everything together, from the central banks at the top of the chain down to the subprime borrowers at the bottom who were given credit because everybody else wanted them to have it.

Get the weekly Five Books newsletter

Their account will upset anybody who thinks you can reduce what happened to a single institutional failure or a single actor. It’s very hard on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. But it’s equally hard on Wall Street, and it’s pretty hard on [Alan] Greenspan, and on the Fed’s refusal to recognise or do anything about the developing credit bubble.

As you said at the beginning, once a bust comes, we get angry about the boom. But surely the human character also has caution baked into it. Why doesn’t the near-certainty of eventual loss deter us sooner – individually or collectively?

There’s a clue in the structure of MacKay’s book. It includes three big financial episodes. But it also takes in some non-financial phenomena, including alchemy and the Crusades, which MacKay views as analogous examples of human irrationality. If MacKay is right, then financial speculation is just one type of a broader human tendency to get caught up in things. People love a party, they love a crowd, they love to get enthusiastic and hopeful about the future. When you’re caught up in a crowd of people speculating, it’s a very exciting business.

“The problem is, of course, that the markets can stay crazy a lot longer than you can stay solvent”

What’s more, when you do get into loss, you will do anything to get out of that loss. As Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky have shown, losers stop being risk averse and start being loss averse. You double up on your bets. Clearly, there are deep-rooted psychological instincts, not only to enjoy speculation, but to carry on speculating even – or especially – when things are going wrong. We all have a bit of the rogue trader in us.

This interview was first published December 20th, 2011

December 20, 2020

Five Books aims to keep its book recommendations and interviews up to date. If you are the interviewee and would like to update your choice of books (or even just what you say about them) please email us at [email protected]

John Gapper

John Gapper

John Gapper is chief business commentator of the Financial Times, where he writes a weekly column. He co-authored All That Glitters, an account of the collapse of Barings bank in 1995. His new e-book is How To Be A Rogue Trader, pegged to the story of a young trader who allegedly ran up $2.3bn of losses

John Gapper

John Gapper

John Gapper is chief business commentator of the Financial Times, where he writes a weekly column. He co-authored All That Glitters, an account of the collapse of Barings bank in 1995. His new e-book is How To Be A Rogue Trader, pegged to the story of a young trader who allegedly ran up $2.3bn of losses